Market Failures And Business Cycles (Part 1)
By R Thotakura
author[at]threewayeconomics.com
Advertisements:
See also: Market Failures And Business
Cycles (Part 2)
The following is the most comprehensive ever explanation to the
most mysterious phenomenon of Capitalism – the Business
Cycles. In order to ensure that the article can be read
by any well educated reader, I have minimized the economics jargon
and have added a short and simple introduction to the structure
of the economy. Each and every one of us would be interested to
know as to why we cannot have a paradise on earth. Why is it that
we are often besieged by such painful downslides of economic activity
such as Great Depression or the nerve wracking periods such as Stagflations?
Why can’t we all be always happy with hundred percent employment
all the time, with each and every one of us employed? The following
article provides simple and complete Business Cycle explanations
to Depressions before 1930s, Recessions
after 1940s, Stagflations of 70s and Continuous
Booms of 80s and 90s.
The income that we earn is normally divided into two portions,
Consumption and Savings. We normally consume a large portion of
the income we earn for our day to day necessities as well as irregular
buys. Regular necessities include food, clothing, toothpastes, soaps
and other daily necessities. Irregular buys include bikes, cars,
books, movies, music and so on. After we spend most of our incomes
on Consumption, we save a small portion of our income and invest
it in shares, bonds, fixed deposits and other long term investments.
In direct relation to our above mentioned activity, our economy
is divided into two sectors – Consumption sector and Investment
sector. If we exclude the government spending, Consumption sector
constitutes roughly around 80% of the size of economy. It includes
everything that we buy – food, clothing, cars, bikes, TVs and other
durable goods, books – every thing. And around 20 percent of the
size our economy is constituted by the Investment sector. Investment
sector mainly includes activities such as installing new plants
and capacities, and housing. A three sector model would also include
government spending as well. However free markets have more to do
with these sectors and less to do with Government Spending, so let
us exclude governemnt spending. The figures given above are only
approximate and can vary sizeably from economy to economy.
So how are profits made by the Consumption sector manufacturers?
In any economy, Consumption sector always produces in excess of
its requirements – it produces surplus. Consumption sector capitalists
as well as households also save a certain portion of their income.
Investors invest these Savings in the Investment sector. So these
Savings turn into the earnings of the Investment sector capitalists
and workers. The workers and capitalists of the Investment sector
then spend their earnings on the consumption goods. So basically
the surplus production of the Consumption sector is consumed by
the workers and capitalists of the Investment sector. Therefore
in a circular flow monetary economy, the income of the Investment
sector becomes the profit or surplus of the Consumption sector firms.
There is a small assumption that is made here on which I shall allude
to at the end of the article.
So there are two things that we have to note here. First the size
of the investment sector decides on the size of the profits of the
Consumption sector. If there are huge Investments made, the Consumption
sector capitalists make huge surpluses or profits and if the size
of the Investment sector is on the lower side, the Consumption sector
capitalists would make lower surpluses or profits. Also all of the
Savings made should always be invested. If Savings are made but
are not invested, then it would lead to a lower size of Investments
and lower profits. Insufficient profits would force the producers
to cut down on their production levels and this would directly lead
to rising unemployment and recession! It is a long recognized economic
thought that Savings made should be compulsorily invested fully
so that the economy can be in equilibrium. If the Savings made are
not invested fully, it can lead to disequilibrium between Supply
and Demand and can lead to piling up of unsold stocks of inventories
and a subsequent recession.
With the above short introduction to the structure of our economy,
we are ready for a small journey into the fascinating world of Business
Cycles.
Our economies are rarely ever static. They keep growing in size
every year. Now in a growing economy Consumption also grows. Year
on year more cars are purchased, more televisions are bought, more
computers are installed and so on. It is natural that when Consumption
grows by say 6%, the suppliers would expect their surplus also to
grow by 6% because surplus, which is called profit in the business
parlance, is obviously measured in percentage terms. However the
surplus production has to be consumed by the workers of the Investment
sector which obviously means that even Investment would have to
grow by 6%. However this would mean that Savings, which is the fund
for Investment, would also have to grow by 6%. What would happen
if Consumption grows by 6% but Investment or Savings do not grow
by an equivalent percentage? To the extent of the inequality, producers’
surplus would remain unsold and the economy would be in disequilibrium.
So the equilibrium condition of the economy would be –
Periodic Growth percentage of Consumption = Periodic growth percentage
of Investment = Periodic growth percentage of Savings.
Suppose during a particular period, there was a perfect equilibrium
in which Consumption was C, Investment was I and Savings was S.
Suppose during the next financial period C grows by a certain X
percentage points. Then S and I would also have to grow by the same
X percentage points. Suppose either I or S does not grow by X percentage
points, the economy would be in disequilibrium even if Investment
is equal to Savings!
Here in lies a blue print for different types of Business
Cycles.
A normal characteristic of any recession is the presence of huge
un-invested Savings. Investors hoard money without investing it
because of lack of investor confidence. At the trough or the lowest
point in a business cycle, Consumption is relatively low and Savings
are relatively high, especially un-invested Savings. Then as economic
activity picks up, all of the Savings are invested and the producers
of the Consumption sector would be able to realize their expected
surpluses. The size of Investment sector is equal to the surplus
of the Consumption sector. Since Savings are high and are fully
invested, the producers of the Consumption sector would be able
to realize huge surpluses. Economic activity picks up a roaring
speed.
As economic activity picks up, there starts a battle amongst the
producers for market shares. For example, each car manufacturer
wants to sell as many cars as possible. He would not think – let
me produce less cars now, let me save and invest more for later.
So as the battle for market share picks up, Consumption accelerates
at the expense of Savings i.e. Consumption grows at a faster rate
than Savings. Our above mentioned condition tells us that for equilibrium
to exist, Consumption and Savings have to grow at an equal pace.
So if Consumption grows at a faster pace than Savings, would this
lead to disequilibrium immediately? This may not immediately lead
to disequilibrium because producers would obviously not keep expecting
to earn abnormally high profits the way they earned in the initial
stages of the boom. Their expectations are also geared towards comparatively
lower profits or what is called as normal profits as the boom progresses
and therefore lower growth rate in Savings vis-à-vis Consumption
would not immediately damage their expectations of surplus. This
way the boom progresses from the trough to the peak for a few years.
After a few years of growth of Consumption at a faster rate than
Savings, the percentage of Savings in the income would drop so low
that Savings are not sufficient to meet the expectations of surplus
of the producers of the Consumption sector. Even if Savings are
fully invested, this does not generate the surplus as expected by
the Consumption sector because of the lower size of investment and
would lead to disequilibrium. Producers see their unsold inventory
stock piles rise and their profits dwindle. The situation needs
correction. Consumption needs to be cut and Savings need to be raised.
As they are not able to sell their goods, the producers of Consumption
sector would be more than willing to do so. They cut their production
and increase their Savings.
However the required correction might not materialize! The very
objective of capitalist economies is Consumption. If Consumption
is on the decline, we cannot expect Investment to increase. We cannot
have fewer bikes sold as compared to previous year and at the same
time have much higher Investment in the bike sector as compared
to the previous year. A cut in Consumption might increase Savings
but would not raise Investment. Investment follows the path of Consumption
and it itself starts in the downward trend. As a result the increased
Savings are not invested and the disequilibrium takes on a relatively
permanent position and we have a recession! There are no automatic
forces to ensure immediate correction. What started with a cut in
Consumption to increase Savings leads to a fall in Investment. This
drop in Investment leads to a further depletion of aggregate demand
which then prompts the producers to cut their production levels
even further. Consumption declines even further and the spiral continues
until the economy settles at a low output with a lot of unemployment.
This sort of downward spirals were recognized by the eminent British
economist John Maynard Keynes. Eventually, after a few years of
low output, some invention or some enthusiastic entrepreneurs who
are attracted by prevalent low interest rates might trigger Investment
to reverse its downward path and start the process of expansion
all over again. I believe that most recessions in US and Europe
after 1940s occurred in this way. I would call these cycles – the
Consumption led Business Cycles.
Something reverse can happen which would be even more damaging
than the just discussed case. Instead of Consumption growing at
a faster rate than Savings, it might so happen that Savings and
Investment grow at a much faster rate than Consumption. For example,
prior to Great Depression, the importance of aggregate demand as
explained by Keynes was not understood. As a result government policies
normally favored huge Investments and were not geared towards propelling
aggregate demand. It is well documented that one of the reasons
for the Great Depression was US government policies which led to
uneven distribution of income heavily in favor of the rich and the
consequent depletion of the buying power of the households. So Great
depression could have easily resulted from Investment/Savings growing
at a much faster rate than Consumption. Huge Investment/Savings
would mean that huge surpluses are realized by the producers of
the Consumption sector. This would prompt them to invest in an even
bigger way in plant and machinery and this huge Investment/surplus
pattern continues for a few years. After a few years, we have huge
capacities with insufficient Consumption or buying power!
The capacities of production rise to an extent where the producers
would not really be interested in investing their surpluses as they
already have huge unutilized capacities much in excess of the buying
power of the households. As a result Savings are not invested i.e.
Investment lags behind Savings. Money is hoarded, the circular flow
of income in the economy stops and the economy gets paralyzed. Demand
gets constricted which in turn constricts Supply. These constrictions
worsen the situation even more because, on account of drop in production,
the percentage of unutilized capacities increases even more than
before which makes Investment in new capacities even more unattractive
further increasing the hoarded money. The economy gets involved
in a vicious downward spiral that can dramatically reduce incomes
and severely aggravate unemployment. Ultimately after a few years,
some huge Investment opportunity prompts entrepreneurs to start
investing all of the Savings and the economy restarts on the expansionary
path. Or it can so happen that the huge excess capacities get destroyed
on account of lack of demand – for example, some new technology
makes plants with older technology unsuitable to the new needs and
such plants and factories become useless. This way excess capacity
is weeded out making the economy conducive for Investment and growth.
I believe that most business cycles in US and Europe prior to 1930s
occurred in this way, they were all mostly Investment propelled.
I would call those cycles – the Investment led Business
cycles.
How can stagflations occur? During the Consumption
led cycles, after several years of growth, Consumption eats away
into Savings and surpluses realized would fall short of expectations
for the producers of Consumption sector. Savings are low and a correction
is required by cutting Consumption and increasing the Savings. The
extent of correction defines the strength of the next boom. If the
correction is big and Savings are piled up in a large manner during
the downturn, then, at the beginning of the next boom, it gives
the chance for Consumption to nibble away at Savings slowly and
steadily for a large number of years – booms can last very long.
If the correction is very small, if Savings are not too large at
the beginning of the boom, the boom is then nipped in the bud itself.
As there are no large Savings made, as soon as Consumption tries
to nibble away Savings, Savings would immediately fall below the
danger mark and the surpluses expected by the Consumption sector
are not realized and a recession would start as immediately as the
boom starts. In such cases, the booms might not last for more than
one or two years. Such cases of insufficient corrections can occur
on account of government intervention. Government tries to arrest
the downward slide by trying to propel the aggregate demand using
expansionary policies such as cutting down interest rates or indulging
in deficit spending. Government’s intention in doing so would be
to arrest the downward slide and decrease unemployment. However
the effect of the government intervention would be that, economy
starts expanding even before the Consumption is cut and Savings
are increased to the required extent. As the economy starts expanding,
Consumption tries to eat away at Savings and this immediately brings
the Savings below the danger level and an immediate onset of recession.
More workers are fired and a downward slide starts once again. Once
again the government intervenes and tries to arrest the slide and
once again the same thing would repeat itself and more workers are
fired. Unemployment keeps soaring. Ultimately the producers realize
that low surpluses are here to stay along with expansion.
Apart from low surpluses there is the problem of rising interest
rates. As the economy tries to expand, there would be good amount
of Investment demand. However as Savings are low and Investment
demand is high, there is a huge demand for the limited funds available
causing the interest rates to rise vertically. Government borrowing
and deficit spending in order to boost the economy eats into the
already low Savings and aggravates the situation even further. The
situation mimics that of a boom time when both short term and long
term interest rates are very high. Abnormally high interest rates
lead to cost-led inflation. Very high interest rates coupled with
low surpluses make Investment as well as production expansion unattractive
to the producers of the Consumption sector. They start pocketing
their profits without either investing or expanding production and
the economy starts stagnating without growth. Under normal circumstances,
pocketing of profits would lead to hoarding of money and paralyze
the economy on account of stoppage in the circulation of money.
However in this case, on account of government’s expansionary policies
as well as cost-led inflation, capitalists do not hoard the money
as money would lose its value on account of inflation. They start
spending the pocketed profits and the circulation of money is not
disrupted.
However the demand does not increase despite the lack of hoarding
– why? What should have been saved and invested is now being spent
directly by the capitalists. The income that would have reached
the hands of a hundred Investment workers is now in the hands of
a single capitalist. As a result, where hundred toothpastes would
have been purchased by hundred Investment workers, only one toothpaste
is purchased by the solitary capitalist! As a result the demand
for goods suffers despite the fact that money is not being hoarded.
Capitalists are high earners; they consume a small portion of their
income and start spending the rest of their income on speculation
in real estate and shares. Shares and lands are bought and re-bought
at higher and higher rates leading to a speculative bubble and soaring
inflation. Housing becomes very costly and the workers find their
buying power reduced as a large portion of their incomes goes in
providing housing for themselves. Workers then start demanding for
higher wages and periodic wage hike agreements become part of the
wage agreements making inflation a relatively permanent phenomenon.
Unlike what some economists say about the unreasonability of wage
hike demands by labor unions, the wage hike demands of workers were
actually beneficial to the stagflationary economies of the 70s.
The hike demands of workers actually act as some sort of a small
check on the speculation of capitalists – instead of wild speculation,
some money in the hands of the capitalists gets diverted towards
wage hikes. Overall, stagnation and inflation co-exist together.
This is how you get stagflation.
There was a continuous boom for two decades in
US and other nations during the 80s and 90s. How could the booms
last so long during this period? The booms during this period were
Investment led. Huge amounts of Investments in IT infrastructure
propelled these booms. However these huge Investments in IT are
completely different from those that propelled the Investment led
booms prior to 1930s. The huge Investments prior to 1930s led to
piling up of new capacities in a big way. This gave in to the chance
of there being over-Investment on account of huge unutilized capacities
which ultimately led to further Investment being unattractive thereby
resulting in Investment lagging behind Savings. However the Investment
of the 80s and 90s was not that way. Investment in IT technology
did not increase the plant capacities. For example, more cars cannot
be produced just because car companies invest huge sums in IT. Therefore
depressions of the type that occurred prior to 1930s are ruled out
and the boom lasts as long as the IT spending lasts. Why couldn’t
Consumption eat into Savings during this period? On account of the
fear of being replaced by computers, the bargaining power of the
workers reduced dramatically upon which wage led and the subsequent
cost led inflations were completely absent. Therefore producers
could save their surpluses and invest them without having to spend
them on increasing costs. Also the prime reason for Investment in
IT being cost cutting, cost cutting ensured that Consumption would
never eat into Savings. This way neither Consumption would eat into
Savings nor would Savings/Investment lead to excess capacities.
Both types of downturns are ruled out. Booms would last as long
as the IT spending would last. This is how booms lasted so long
during the 80s and the 90s leading to a virtual absence of business
cycles.
That roughly sums up two and half centuries of Business
Cycles!
A small note before closing out. From the capitalists’ point of
view, it would be great if the households immediately spend all
that they earn on Consumption – sales would get boosted. So household
savings make a dent or a hole in Consumption. This hole is then
filled by the immediate Investment of those household Savings. So
the phenomenon of investing the household Savings is like digging
a hole and filling it up. Therefore household Savings do not affect
the financial position of an economy as much as the Capitalist Savings.
A shrinkage in household Savings would not directly affect the margins
of the firms. So just make a mental note that the above discussion
on Savings had more to do with Capitalist Savings and less to do
with Household Savings.
© 2005 Thotakura R,US registration:TXU 1-256-191
About the Author: Thotakura R is the originator
a new revolutionary economic model called "Threeway Economics"
that demystifies the longstanding mysteries of capitalism to a great
level of detail including Business Cycles,Inverted Yield Curves,Inflations,Price/Wage
rigidities. To learn more, Visit his site at: http://www.threewayeconomics.com
Source: www.isnare.com
Published - November 2005
|